Transnational/Multinational Corporations in the Global Economy

International corporations have several categories depending on the business structure, investment and product/ service offerings. Transnational companies (TNC) and multinational companies (MNC) are two of a these categories. Both MNC and TNC are enterprises that manage production or delivers services in more than one country. They are characterized as business entities that have their management headquarters in one country, known as the home country, and operate in several other countries, known as host countries. Industries like manufacturing, oil mining, agriculture, consulting, accounting, construction, legal, advertising, entertainment, banking, telecommunications and lodging are often run through TNC’s and MNC’s. The said corporations maintain various bases all over the world. Many of them are owned by a mixture of domestic and foreign stock holders. Most TNC’s and MNC’s are massive with budgets that outweigh smaller nations’ GDPs. Thus, TNC and MNC alike are highly influential to globalization, economic and environmental lobbying in most countries. Because of their influence, countries and regional political districts at times tender incentives to MNC and TNC in form of tax breaks, pledges of governmental assistance or improved infrastructure, political favors and lenient environmental and labor standards enforcement in order to be at an advantage from their competitors. Also due to their size, they can have a significant impact on government policy, primarily through the threat of market withdrawal. They are powerful enough to initiate lobbying that is directed at a variety of business concerns such as tariff structures, aiming to restrict competition of foreign industries. Some of the top TNC’s and MNC’s are General Electric, Toyota Motor, Total, Royal Dutch Shell, ExxonMobil and Vodafone Group
Moreover, a lot of people often interchange MNC and TNC or misconstrue them to be one and the same to pertain to a company that owns production facilities in two or more countries, with the only difference that the former being the original terminology. Contrary to this popular notion, they are of different kinds. TNC has been technically defined by United Nations Commission on Transnational Corporations and Investment as ‘enterprises which own or control production or service facilities outside the country in which they are based.” The committee has also placed its preference on the term TNC. MNC, on the other hand, is the older term and popularly remains to be the generic label for firms similar to TNC and MNC. Here’s the significant difference, though. Multinational companies (MNC) have investment in other countries, but do not have coordinated product offerings in each country. They are more focused on adapting their products and service to each individual local market. Well-known MNC’s are mostly consumer goods manufacturers and quick-service restaurants like Unilever, Proctor & Gamble, Mc Donald’s and Seven-Eleven. On another note, Transnational companies (TNC) are much more complex firms. They have invested in foreign operations, have a central corporate facility but give decision-making, R&D and marketing powers to each individual foreign market. Most of them come from petroleum, I.T. consulting, pharmaceutical industries among others. Examples are Shell, Accenture, Deloitte, Glaxo-Smith Klein, and Roche.

Summary
1) Multinational (MNC) and Transnational (TNC) companies are types of international corporations. Both maintain management headquarters in one country, known as the home country, and operate in several other countries, known as host countries.
2) Most TNC’s and MNC’s are massive in terms of budget and are highly influential to globalization. They are also considered as main drivers of the local economy, government policies, environmental and political lobbying
3) An MNC have investment in other countries, but do not have coordinated product offerings in each country. It is more focused on adapting their products and service to each individual local market. A TNC, on the other hand, have invested in foreign operations, have a central corporate facility but give decision-making, R&D and marketing powers to each individual foreign market.
A multinational corporation or worldwide enterprise is a corporate organization that owns or controls production of goods or services in two or more countries other than their home country.
Transnational corporations (TNCs) are incorporated or unincorporated enterprises comprising parent enterprises and their foreign affiliates. A parent enterprise is defined as an enterprise that controls assets of other entities in countries other than its home country, usually by owning a certain equity capital stake.
Please note that MNC has an international identity as belonging to a particular home country where they are headquartered. A transnational company is borderless, as it does not consider any particular country as its base, home or headquarters. Transnational corporations are a type of multinational corporations.
Multinational corporations sit at the intersection of production, international trade, and cross-border investment.  A multinational corporation is “an enterprise that engages in foreign direct investment (FDI) and owns or controls value adding activities in more than one country” (Dunning 1993, 3).  MNCs thus have two characteristics.  First, they coordinate economic production among a number of different enterprises and internalize this coordination problem within a single firm structure.  Second, a significant portion of the economic transactions connected with this coordinated activity take place across national borders.  These two attributes distinguish MNCs from other firms. While many firms control and coordinate the production of multiple enterprises, and while many other firms engage in economic transactions across borders, MNCs are the only firms that coordinate and internalize economic activity across national borders.
It is difficult to exaggerate the importance of MNCs in the contemporary global economy.  In discussing MNCs it is typical to distinguish between parent firms, the corporate owner of the network of firms comprising the MNC, and the foreign affiliates, the multiple enterprises owned by parent firms.  This basic terminology allows us to gain a sense of the role that MNCs play in the contemporary international economy.  According to the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, there are approximately 63,459 parent firms that together own a total of 689,520 foreign affiliates.  In 1998 these affiliates employed approximately 6 million people worldwide.  Together, parent firms and their foreign affiliates produce about 25 percent of world gross domestic product (UNCTAD 2000).  The importance of multinational corporations is not limited to production, as they are also significant participants in international trade.  It has been estimated that trade within MNCs, called intra-firm trade, accounts for about one-third of total world trade.  If we add to this figure the trade that takes place between MNCs and other unaffiliated firms, then MNCs are involved in about two-thirds of world trade.  Thus, MNCs are productive enterprises that by definition engage in cross-border investment and are heavily involved in international trade. Who are these firms, and where are they located?  While it is impossible to provide an extensive catalog of more than 60,000 firms, table 5.2 does list the world’s 100 largest MNCs, ranked by their foreign assets.  These 100 MNCs, among which are many familiar names, account for more than 15 percent of all foreign assets controlled by all MNCs, and for 22 percent of total sales by MNCs.  These large MNCs are based almost exclusively in advanced industrialized countries; ninety-nine of the 100 largest firms are from the United States, Western Europe, or Japan and more than 5/6ths of all parent corporations are based in advanced industrial countries (see table 5.3).  Parent corporations are not exclusively a developed country phenomenon, however.  Hong Kong, China, South Korea, Venezuela, Mexico, and Brazil are also home to MNC parent firms, but these firms are considerably smaller than developed country firms.  Only one MNC parent based in a developing country, Petroleos de Venezuela, ranks among the world’s 100 largest.  The fifty largest MNCs from developing countries control only $105 billion of foreign assets, less than ten percent of the assets controlled by the 50 largest developed country MNCs. The distribution is reversed when we consider the affiliates.  Developing countries host more than 355,324 MNC affiliates, while advanced industrialized countries host only 94,269 (UNCTAD 2000, 11-13).  Within the developing world, MNC affiliates are
           








Table 5.2:  The Fifty Largest MNCs, Ranked by Foreign Assets

Firm    Country          Industry         Foreign           Total   Foreign
Assets                                     Assets                                                                                                                                                                                                 Employment
General Electric
United States
Electronics
97.4
304.0
111,000
Ford Motor Company
United States
Automotive
72.5
275.4
174,105
Royal Dutch Shell
Netherlands/UK
Petroleum
70
115
65,000
General Motors
United States
Automotive



Exxon Corp
United States
Petroleum
54.6
96.1

Toyota
Japan
Automotive
41.8
105.0

IBM
United States
Computer
39.9
81.5
134,815
Volkswagen Group
Germany
Automotive

57.0
133,906
Nestle S.A.
Switzerland
Food and Beverages
31.6
47.6
219,442
Daimler-Benz
Germany
Automotive
30.9
76.2
74,802
Mobil
United States 
Petroleum
30.4
43.6
22,200
Fiat Spa
Italy
Automotive
30
69.1
94,877
Hoechst AG
Germany
Chemicals
29.0
34.0

Asea Brown Boveri (ABB)
Switzerland
Electrical Equipment

29.8
200,574
Bayer AG
Germany
Chemicals

30.3

Elf Aquitaine SA
France
Petroleum
26.7
42.0
40,500
Nissan Motor
Japan
Automotive
26.5
57.6

Unilever
Netherlands/Uk
Food and Bev
25.6
30.8
262,840
Siemens AG
Germany
Electronics
25.6
67.1
201,141
Roche Holding AG
Switzerland
Pharmaceuticals

37.6
41,832
Sony Corp
Japan
Electronics

48.2

Mitsubishi
Japan
Diversified
21.9
67.1

Seagram
Canada
Beverages
21.8
22.2

Honda Motor
Japan
Automotive
21.5
36.5

BMW AG
Germany
Automotive
20.3
31.8
52,149
Alcatel
France
Electronics
20.3
41.9

Philips Electronics
Netherlands
Electronics
20.1
25.5
206,236

News Corp
Australia
Media
20.0
30.7

Phillip Morris
United States 
Food/Tobacco
19.4
55.9

British Petroleum
UK
Petroleum
19.2
32.6
37,600
Hewlett-Packard
United States 
Electronics
18.5
31.7

Total SA
France
Petrloeum

25.2

Renault SA
France
Automotive
18.3
34.9
45,860
Cable and Wireless Plc
UK
Telecommunication

21.6
33,740
Mitsui &Co. Ltd
Japan
Diversified
17.9
55.5

Rhone-Poulenc SA
France
Chemicals/Pharmaceuticals
17.8
27.5

Viag SA
Germany
Diversified
17.4
32.7

BASF AG
Germany 
Chemicals

26.8

Itochu Corp
Japan
Trading
16.7
56.8
2,600
Nassho Iwei Corp
Japan
Trading
16.6
40.4
2,068
Du Pont
United States
Chemicals
16.6
42.7

Diageo Plc
UK
Beverages

29.7
63,761
Novartis
Switzerland
Pharmaceuticals/Chemicals
16.0
36.7
71,403
Sumitomo Corp
Japan
Trading/machinery
15.4
43.0

ENI Group
Italy
Petroleum
14.6
49.4
23,239
Chevron Corp
United States 
Petroleum
14.3
35.5
8,610
Dow Chemical
United States
Chemicals
14.3
23.6

Texaco Inc
United States 
Petroleum
14.1
29.6

BCE Inc
Canada
Telecommunication
13.6
28.2

Xerox
United States 
Photo Equipment
13.5
27.7


Source:  United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 1999.

Table 5.3: Parent Corporations and Affiliates By Region
            Parent Corporations             Foreign Affiliates
Based in Economy     Located in Economy

Developed Economies


     Western Europe
37,580
61,594
     United States
3,387
19,103
     Japan
4,334
3,321
Developing Economies


     Africa
167
3,669
     Latin America and Caribbean
2,019
24,345
     Asia
9,883
327,310
     Central and Eastern Europe
2,150
239,927
Source: UNCTAD 2000, 11-13.
 
highly concentrated in a relatively small set of countries.  Thirteen countries in East Asia and Latin America host 331,748 MNC affiliates, about half of the total affiliates worldwide.  China alone hosts 235,681 affiliates.  MNCs have also invested heavily in Eastern and Central Europe during the 1990s, creating a total of 239,927 affiliates in this region.  Here too affiliates are concentrated in a few countries; the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Poland host 135,997 of the affiliates active in this region.  While these figures on the location of affiliates are interesting, they are misleading to some extent.  As we saw in chapter four, the vast majority of foreign direct investment flows into advanced industrialized countries rather than the developing world.  Thus, even though there are more affiliates based in developing countries than in advanced industrialized countries, the affiliates created in advanced industrialized countries tend to be larger and more capital intensive than the affiliates created in developing countries.
For what specific purposes do firms engage in foreign direct investment? MNC investment can be divided into three broad categories.  First, MNCs engage in crossborder investment to gain secure access to supplies of natural resources.  For example, the American copper mining firm Anaconda made large direct investments in mining operations in Chile in order to secure copper supplies for production done in the United States.  Indeed, as table 5.4 illustrates, petroleum and mining is the third most important industry represented in the top 100 MNCs, with 11 of the largest firms engaged in either oil production or mining.
Second, MNCs invest across borders to gain access to foreign markets.  Much of the cross-border investment in auto production undertaken within the advanced industrialized world fits into this category.  During the 1980s and early 1990s, Japanese
Table 5.4: Industry Composition of the Top 100 MNCs
                                                                                                                        1990    1998
Electronics/electrical equipment/computers
14
17
Motor Vehicle and Parts
13
14
Petroleum (exploration, refining, distribution) and Mining
13
11
Food, Beverages, Tobacco
9
10
Chemicals
12
8
Pharmaceuticals
6
8
Diversified
2
6
Telecommunications
2
6
Trading
7
4
Retailing
-
3
Utilities
-
3
Metals
6
2
Media
2
2
Construction
4
1
Machinery/engineering
3
-
Other
7
5
Total
100
100
Source: UNCTAD 2000, 78.

and German automotive MNCs such as Toyota, Nissan, Honda, BMW, and Mercedes
built production facilities in the United States in response to concerns that barriers to market access would limit the number of cars they would be allowed to export into the American economy from Japanese and German plants.  During the 1960s, many American MNCs made direct investments in the European Union to gain access to the common market being created there.  As table 5.4 indicates, the auto industry is the second most heavily represented industry among the largest MNCs, accounting for 14 of the top 100 MNCs.
Third, MNCs make cross-border investments to improve the efficiency of their operations, by rationalizing production and trying to exploit economies of specialization and scope.  An increasingly large share of cross-border investment in manufacturing fits into this category.  In electronics and computers as well as in the auto industry, firms allocate different elements of the production process to different parts of the world.  In computers, electronics, and electrical equipment, for example, which account for seventeen of the largest 100 MNCs (see table 5.4), the human and physical capital intensive stages of production such as design and chip fabrication, are performed in the advanced industrialized countries, while the more labor-intensive assembly stages of production are performed in developing countries.  In the auto industry, the capital intensive design and production of individual parts such as body panels, engines, and transmissions is performed in developed countries, and the more labor-intensive assembly of the individual components into automobiles is performed in developing countries.
Multinational corporations’ activities in the postwar international economy have evolved over time.  It is common to divide this evolution into two distinct periods, the immediate postwar period spanning the years 1945 to 1960 and a second period since 1960.  Two features characterized the immediate postwar period.  First, American firms dominated foreign direct investment.  Concerned with postwar reconstruction and unwilling to risk the balance of payments consequences of capital outflows, European and Japanese governments had little interest in encouraging outward direct investment.  As a consequence, American firms dominated MNC activity, accounting for about two thirds of the new affiliates created in this period.  Second, the bulk of MNC investment during this period was oriented toward Europe for the purpose of manufacturing.  The push to invest in Europe was given additional impetus at the end of the 1950s by the creation of the European Economic Community, and thus the early 1960s saw a rapid increase in the amount of market-oriented investment by American firms in the Common
Market countries.  Other direct investments flowed to developing countries, Canada, and Australia for natural resource extraction.  In short, American MNCs engaged primarily in market- and natural resource-oriented foreign direct investment dominated the immediate postwar period.
Both of these characteristics of MNC activity have changed dramatically since 1960.  The early dominance of American firms has been increasingly diminished as European and Japanese firms began to engage in foreign direct investment.  The increased role of other industrialized nations has more recently been accompanied by the emergence of foreign direct investment by MNCs based in the Asian NICs and in Latin America.  Thus, while American firms continue to play a large role, they are not nearly as dominant today as they were in the early postwar years.  At the same time, the relative importance of market- and natural resource-oriented direct investment has fallen and that of efficiency-oriented investment has risen.  As Dunning (1996) notes, MNCs increasingly view “each of their foreign affiliates and, frequently, their associated suppliers and industrial customers, not as self-contained entities, but as part of a regional or global network of activities.  New investments are increasingly undertaken as part of an integrated international production system.” The shift to efficiency-oriented investments and integrated international production systems has been made possible in large part by developments in communications technology and, as we saw in chapter four, by the reduction in trade barriers achieved through the GATT process. In summary, during the last fifty years multinational corporations have grown to play a centrally important role in the international economy.  MNCs are, in many respects, the driving force behind the deepening integration of the global economy.  The central importance of MNCs in the contemporary international economy raises a large number of issues that we explore in the pages that follow.  Most of these issues can be subsumed under a single question:  What are the economic and political consequences of MNC activity?  To answer this question we look first at the economics of multinational corporations, examining why firms engage in foreign direct investment and how FDI affects economic activity in the countries that host it.  We then turn our attention to the political economy of MNCs, examining the nature of the bargaining relationship between MNCs and host-country governments and governments’ efforts, unsuccessful to date, to craft an international investment regime.
 The Costs and Benefits of MNC Activity
How are host countries affected by MNC activity? While it is clear that MNCs are motivated to engage in foreign direct investment to raise their profitability, it is less obvious what impact these investments have on the countries that receive them.  In fact, most of the controversy surrounding MNC activity arises from disputes over how foreign direct investment affects the host country.  Some argue that FDI is highly beneficial to the host country, while others argue that MNCs have a negative impact on host countries, particularly in the developing world.  Here we look closely at two well-developed perspectives on the impact of foreign direct investment on host countries and then briefly consider what the existing empirical evidence suggests about the accuracy of these competing perspectives.
The Benign model argues that MNCs make a significant contribution to economic development.  Foreign direct investment is an important mechanism through which savings are transferred from the advanced industrialized world to the developing world.  Because developing countries usually have low savings, FDI can usefully add to the capital available for physical investment.  Moreover, because MNCs create fixed investments, this form of cross-border capital flow is not subject to the problems often posed by financial capital flows.  Fixed investment is substantially less volatile than financial capital flows, and thus does not generate the kinds of boom and bust cycles we saw in chapter 8.  In addition, because MNCs invest by creating domestic affiliates, direct investment does not raise host countries’ external indebtedness.  Of the many possible ways in which savings can be transferred to the developing world, therefore, direct investment might be the most stable and least burdensome for the recipient countries.
The benign model also suggests that MNCs are important vehicles for the transfer of technology to host countries.  Because MNCs control proprietary assets, which are often based on specialized knowledge, the investments they make in developing countries often lead to this knowledge being transferred to indigenous firms.  In Malaysia, for example, Motorola Malaysia transferred the technology required to produce a particular type of printed circuit board to a Malaysian firm, which then developed the capacity to produce these circuit boards on its own (Moran 1999, 77-8).  In the absence of the technology transfer, the indigenous firm would not have been able to produce these products.  Technology transfer can in turn generate significant positive externalities with wider implications for development (see Graham 1996, 123-130).  Externalities arise when economic actors in the host country that are not directly involved in the MNC-local affiliate technology transfer also gain from this transaction.  If the Malaysian Motorola affiliate, for example, was able to use the technology it acquired from Motorola to produce inputs for other Malaysian firms at a lower cost than these inputs were available elsewhere, then the technology transfer would have a positive externality on the Malaysian economy.
In addition to transferring technology, the benign model suggests that MNCs transfer managerial expertise to developing countries.  Greater experience at managing large firms allows MNC personnel to organize production and coordinate the activities of multiple enterprises more efficiently than host country managers.  This knowledge is applied to the host country affiliates, allowing them to operate more efficiently as well.  Indigenous managers in these affiliates can then move to indigenous firms, spreading managerial expertise into the host country.
Finally, the benign model suggests that MNCs enable developing country producers to gain access to marketing networks.  When direct investments are made as part of a global production strategy, the local affiliates of the MNC and the domestic firms that supply the MNC affiliate become integrated into a global marketing chain. 
This opens up export opportunities that indigenous producers would not otherwise have.  The Malaysian firm to which Motorola transferred the printed circuit board technology, for example, wound up supplying not only Motorola Malaysia, but also began to supply these components to eleven Motorola plants worldwide.  These opportunities would not have arisen had the firm not been able to link up with Motorola Malaysia.
The Malign model focuses on many of the same elements as the benign model, but argues that these factors often operate to the detriment of host country economic development.  First, rather than transferring savings to developing countries, the malign model argues that MNCs reduce domestic savings.  Savings are reduced in two ways.  First, it is argued that MNCs often borrow on the host country capital market rather than bring capital from their home country.  MNC investment therefore “crowds out” rather than adding to domestic investment.  Second, it is suggested that MNCs earn rents— above normal profits—on their products and repatriate most of these earnings.  Host country consumers therefore pay too much for the goods they buy, with negative consequences on individual savings, while MNC profits, which could potentially be a source of savings and investment in the host country, are transferred back to the home country.  The amount of domestic savings available to finance projects therefore falls.
The malign model also argues that MNCs exert tight control over technology and managerial positions, preventing the transfer of both.  The logic here is simple.  As we saw above, one of the principal reasons for MNC investment arises from the desire to maintain control over proprietary assets.  Given this, it is indeed hard to understand why an MNC would make a large fixed investment in order to retain control over proprietary technology, and then once having done so begin to transfer this technology to host country firms.  Managerial expertise is not readily transferred either, in large part because MNCs are reluctant to hire host-country residents into top-level managerial positions.  Thus, the second purported benefit of MNC—the transfer of technology and managerial expertise—can be stymied by the very logic that causes MNCs to undertake FDI.
Finally, the malign model suggests that MNCs can drive domestic producers out of business.  This can happen in one of two ways.  On the one hand, domestic firms producing in the same sector will face increased competition once an MNC begins selling in the domestic market.  Using best practices for management and state of the art technology, MNCs can often under-price local firms, thereby driving them out of business.  Second, MNCs often desire to assemble their finished goods from imported components.  As a result, domestic input producers in the same industry will find that as the domestic producers they supply are driven out of business, they have no one to sell their intermediate goods.  Thus, local input suppliers can also be driven out of business by MNCs.
The benign and the malign models depict dramatically different consequences from MNC/TNC investment in developing country economies.  Which of these two models is correct?  The short answer is that both are; foreign direct investment is sometimes beneficial for and at other times detrimental to the host countries.  Two studies, now somewhat outdated, are suggestive in this regard.  One study examined 88 MNC affiliates operating in six countries (Lall and Streeten 1977).  The authors found that in two-thirds of the cases foreign direct investment had a positive impact on the host country, and in one-third of the cases the impact was negative.  A similar study was conducted about ten years later.  Focusing on 50 foreign direct investments, this study found that between half and three quarters of the foreign investments yielded net benefits to the host countries, while one-quarter to one-half of the projects imposed net costs onto the host country (Encarnation and Wells 1986).  Thus, foreign direct investment sometimes operates in the manner suggested by the benign model, and at other times it operates as the malign model suggests.
What determines whether any particular investment will be beneficial or detrimental to the host country?  It is extremely difficult to say anything systematic or conclusive in response to this question.  A range of considerations are important, including the specific agreement between the host-country government and the MNC upon which the investment is based.  While any broad generalizations must therefore be treated with considerable caution, one can suggest that some types of investment begin with a bias against host country development while other types of investment do not carry an initial bias.  Market oriented and natural resource investments both carry biases that can limit the contribution they make to economic development in host countries.  First, both types of investment take place under conditions of limited competition.  Foreign affiliates in the extractive industries often gain monopoly control over the resource deposits of a given country, for example, while affiliates producing for the host-country market are often protected from external competition by high tariffs.  The absence of competition results in large rents accruing to firms operating in these areas, with associated efficiency losses for the host country.  Moreover, both types of investment can have a negative impact on domestic producers in the host country.  UNCTAD suggests, for example, that recent investments by MNCs in copper mining in Chile may have substituted for investments that otherwise would have been made by the Chilean national copper company (CODELCO), “which is the largest copper mining enterprise in the world and operates with state-of-the-art technology” (UNCTAD 1999, 173).  Finally, neither resource oriented nor market oriented investment offers many opportunities for domestic producers to link into international marketing networks.  For all of these reasons we might expect host countries to be most likely to suffer costs from natural resource and market-oriented investments.
Efficiency-oriented investments seem to carry fewer of the biases and offer the greatest chance that MNC activity will have a positive impact on host countries.  The industries in which these investments occur are usually quite competitive internationally, hence the MNC’s drive for cost reduction measures, and the level of rents is correspondingly lower.  Such investments can (but don’t always) create backward linkages to domestic input producers, and thus can promote rather than retard local firm growth.  In particular, efficiency-oriented investments often “crowd-in” rather than “crowd out” investments by domestic firms.  For example, it has been estimated that Intel’s decision to construct a microprocessor plant in Costa Rica will likely give rise to additional investments by 40 Costa Rican firms (UNCTAD 1999, 172).  Finally, the international orientation of such firms creates opportunities for local firms to link themselves to global marketing networks.  The research reported by Encarnation and Wells (1986) is consistent with the notion that efficiency-oriented investments contain fewer of the biases against development that are present in natural resource and market oriented investments.  All of the export-oriented projects in the sample of MNC affiliates that they examined provided benefits to the host country.  For all of these reasons we might expect host countries to benefit the most from efficiency-oriented investments.
The case of Singer Sewing Machines experience in Taiwan is suggestive of the potential benefits available through well-managed foreign direct investment.  Singer first began producing in Taiwan in 1964.[1]  At the time there were a number of local sewing machine producers using old technology and lacking standardization and therefore unable to compete in international markets.  As a condition of Singer’s investment, the Taiwanese government imposed domestic content requirements, insisting that Singer source 83 percent of its parts from Taiwanese producers within one year.  In addition, the Taiwanese government imposed substantial conditions to ensure technology transfers.  Singer was required to provide the local parts producers with standardized blueprints, and make available technical experts to assist in local firms’ efforts to produce the specified parts.  In addition, Singer was obliged to allow Taiwanese sewing machine producers to use the same parts it sourced from local parts producers at a cost close to the world price for these parts.  Finally, an export requirement was imposed; Singer was required to increase its exports from Taiwan rapidly.
Singer complied with all of these requirements.  Technical and management experts were dispatched to train local parts producers and to reorganize the production system within Taiwan.  Technical assistance was also provided to local sewing machine producers—the very firms that comprised Singer’s competition—at no cost to these firms.  Blueprints and part specifications were provided to all local parts producers, thereby allowing them to work to common specifications and standards.  Finally, Singer held classes for local parts producers in the technical and managerial aspects of the business.
As a direct result of these measures, substantial transfers of technology occurred, and significant backward linkages between the final sewing machine producers and the parts suppliers occurred.  By the late 1960s Singer was sourcing all of the parts for its sewing machines produced in Taiwan from Taiwanese firms (except the needles).  Moreover, 86 percent of Singer’s local production was exported.  In addition, Taiwanese sewing machine producers became more competitive internationally.  As local parts became standardized and of greater quality, Taiwanese sewing machine producers also became able to export to foreign markets.
In summary, MNC/TNC activity is sometimes beneficial for host country economic development, and at other times is detrimental to such development.  One might suggest that natural resource investments are the least likely to offer substantial benefits to host countries, while efficiency oriented investments are the most likely to offer substantial benefits to host countries.  Market oriented investments are likely to fall somewhere in between these two types, sometimes offering benefits, and at other times imposing costs.  It is important to re-emphasize the tentativeness of these broad generalizations.  The point must be made that MNC/TNC activity has historically been subject to political considerations.  As a consequence, the impact of any particular investment on any particular host country is shaped by the particular agreement between the firm and the host country government.  These agreements can transform a natural resource investment into a highly beneficial proposition for a host country, and they can transform an efficiency-oriented investment into a highly costly one.  In other words, while the preceding discussion is suggestive, the effect that any particular foreign direct investment will have on any particular host country will depend greatly on the specific details of the case.

References
Caves, Richard E. 1996.  Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis.  Cambridge:  Cambridge University Press.
Dunning, John H.  1996. “Re-evaluating the Benefits of Foreign Direct Investment,” in Companies without Borders:  Transnational Corporations in the 1990s, edited by UNCTAD. (London:  International Thomson Business Press), pp. 73-101.
Graham, Edward M. 1996. Global Corporations and National Governments. Washington, D.C.:  Institute for International Economics.
Hymer, Stephen. 1976. The international operations of national firms: a study of direct foreign investment.  Cambridge: MIT Press.
Kindleberger, Charles P. 1969.  Six Lectures on Direct Investment. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Kobrin, Stephen. 1987.  “Testing the Bargaining Hypothesis in the Manufacturing Sector in Developing Countries,” International Organization 41 (autumn): 609-638.
Moran, Theodore H. 1999. Foreign Direct Investment and Development: The New Policy Agenda for Developing Countries and Economies in Transition. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
Moran, Theodore H. 1974. Multinational corporations and the politics of dependence: Copper in Chile. Princeton, N.J., Princeton University Press. 
Stopford, John M. 1996. “The Growing Interdependence Between Transnational
Corporations and Governments,” in Companies without Borders:  Transnational Corporations in the 1990s, edited by UNCTAD. (London:  International Thomson Business Press), pp. 255-79.
Teece, David J. 1993, “The Multinational Enterprise:  Market Failure and Market Power Considerations,” in The Theory of Transnational Corporations, John Dunning, editor.  New York:  Routledge, pp. 163-182.
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. 2000. World Investment Report: Cross-border Mergers and Acquisitions and Development.  Geneva: The United Nations.
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. 1999. World Investment Report:  Foreign Direct Investment and the Challenge of Development.  Geneva: The United Nations.
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. 1995. World Investment Report: Transnational Corporations and Competitiveness.  Geneva: The United Nations.
Vernon, Raymond. 1971. Sovereignty at Bay: the Multinational Spread of U.S.
Enterprises.  New York: Basic Books.



[1] Based on UNCTAD 1999, 211. 

Comments

Post a Comment

Popular posts from this blog

Public Administration in Nigeria

NOTES ON NIGERIAN GOVERNMENT AND POLITICS

Short Notes on POS 407 - Politics and Law in Africa