Transnational/Multinational Corporations in the Global Economy
International
corporations have several categories depending on the business structure,
investment and product/ service offerings. Transnational companies (TNC) and
multinational companies (MNC) are two of a these categories. Both MNC and TNC
are enterprises that manage production or delivers services in more than one
country. They are characterized as business entities that have their management
headquarters in one country, known as the home country, and operate in several
other countries, known as host countries. Industries like manufacturing, oil
mining, agriculture, consulting, accounting, construction, legal, advertising,
entertainment, banking, telecommunications and lodging are often run through
TNC’s and MNC’s. The said corporations maintain various bases all over the
world. Many of them are owned by a mixture of domestic and foreign stock
holders. Most TNC’s and MNC’s are massive with budgets that outweigh smaller
nations’ GDPs. Thus, TNC and MNC alike are highly influential to globalization,
economic and environmental lobbying in most countries. Because of their
influence, countries and regional political districts at times tender
incentives to MNC and TNC in form of tax breaks, pledges of governmental
assistance or improved infrastructure, political favors and lenient
environmental and labor standards enforcement in order to be at an advantage
from their competitors. Also due to their size, they can have a significant
impact on government policy, primarily through the threat of market withdrawal.
They are powerful enough to initiate lobbying that is directed at a variety of
business concerns such as tariff structures, aiming to restrict competition of
foreign industries. Some of the top TNC’s and MNC’s are General Electric,
Toyota Motor, Total, Royal Dutch Shell, ExxonMobil and Vodafone Group
Moreover, a lot of people often interchange
MNC and TNC or misconstrue them to be one and the same to pertain to a company
that owns production facilities in two or more countries, with the only
difference that the former being the original terminology. Contrary to this
popular notion, they are of different kinds. TNC has been technically defined
by United Nations Commission on Transnational Corporations and Investment as
‘enterprises which own or control production or service facilities outside the
country in which they are based.” The committee has also placed its preference
on the term TNC. MNC, on the other hand, is the older term and popularly
remains to be the generic label for firms similar to TNC and MNC. Here’s the
significant difference, though. Multinational companies (MNC) have investment
in other countries, but do not have coordinated product offerings in each
country. They are more focused on adapting their products and service to each
individual local market. Well-known MNC’s are mostly consumer goods
manufacturers and quick-service restaurants like Unilever, Proctor &
Gamble, Mc Donald’s and Seven-Eleven. On another note, Transnational companies
(TNC) are much more complex firms. They have invested in foreign operations,
have a central corporate facility but give decision-making, R&D and
marketing powers to each individual foreign market. Most of them come from
petroleum, I.T. consulting, pharmaceutical industries among others. Examples
are Shell, Accenture, Deloitte, Glaxo-Smith Klein, and Roche.
Summary
1) Multinational (MNC) and Transnational (TNC) companies are types of international corporations. Both maintain management headquarters in one country, known as the home country, and operate in several other countries, known as host countries.
2) Most TNC’s and MNC’s are massive in terms of budget and are highly influential to globalization. They are also considered as main drivers of the local economy, government policies, environmental and political lobbying
3) An MNC have investment in other countries, but do not have coordinated product offerings in each country. It is more focused on adapting their products and service to each individual local market. A TNC, on the other hand, have invested in foreign operations, have a central corporate facility but give decision-making, R&D and marketing powers to each individual foreign market.
1) Multinational (MNC) and Transnational (TNC) companies are types of international corporations. Both maintain management headquarters in one country, known as the home country, and operate in several other countries, known as host countries.
2) Most TNC’s and MNC’s are massive in terms of budget and are highly influential to globalization. They are also considered as main drivers of the local economy, government policies, environmental and political lobbying
3) An MNC have investment in other countries, but do not have coordinated product offerings in each country. It is more focused on adapting their products and service to each individual local market. A TNC, on the other hand, have invested in foreign operations, have a central corporate facility but give decision-making, R&D and marketing powers to each individual foreign market.
Read more: Difference Between TNC and MNC | Difference Between http://www.differencebetween.net/business/difference-between-tnc-and-mnc/#ixzz4yPrkKo6e
A multinational corporation or worldwide
enterprise is a corporate organization that owns or controls production of
goods or services in two or more countries other than their home country.
Transnational corporations (TNCs)
are incorporated or unincorporated enterprises comprising parent enterprises
and their foreign affiliates. A parent enterprise is defined as an enterprise
that controls assets of other entities in countries other than its home
country, usually by owning a certain equity capital stake.
Please note that MNC has an
international identity as belonging to a particular home country where they are
headquartered. A transnational company is borderless, as it
does not consider any particular country as its base, home or
headquarters. Transnational corporations are a type of multinational
corporations.
Multinational corporations sit at the intersection of production,
international trade, and cross-border investment. A multinational corporation is “an enterprise
that engages in foreign direct investment (FDI) and owns or controls value
adding activities in more than one country” (Dunning 1993, 3). MNCs thus have two characteristics. First, they coordinate economic production
among a number of different enterprises and internalize this coordination
problem within a single firm structure.
Second, a significant portion of the economic transactions connected
with this coordinated activity take place across national borders. These two attributes distinguish MNCs from
other firms. While many firms control and coordinate the production of multiple
enterprises, and while many other firms engage in economic transactions across
borders, MNCs are the only firms that coordinate and internalize economic
activity across national borders.
It is
difficult to exaggerate the importance of MNCs in the contemporary global
economy. In discussing MNCs it is
typical to distinguish between parent firms, the corporate owner of the network
of firms comprising the MNC, and the foreign affiliates, the multiple
enterprises owned by parent firms. This
basic terminology allows us to gain a sense of the role that MNCs play in the
contemporary international economy.
According to the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development,
there are approximately 63,459 parent firms that together own a total of
689,520 foreign affiliates. In 1998
these affiliates employed approximately 6 million people worldwide. Together, parent firms and their foreign
affiliates produce about 25 percent of world gross domestic product (UNCTAD
2000). The importance of multinational
corporations is not limited to production, as they are also significant
participants in international trade. It
has been estimated that trade within MNCs, called intra-firm trade, accounts
for about one-third of total world trade.
If we add to this figure the trade that takes place between MNCs and
other unaffiliated firms, then MNCs are involved in about two-thirds of world
trade. Thus, MNCs are productive
enterprises that by definition engage in cross-border investment and are
heavily involved in international trade. Who are these firms, and where are
they located? While it is impossible to
provide an extensive catalog of more than 60,000 firms, table 5.2 does list the
world’s 100 largest MNCs, ranked by their foreign assets. These 100 MNCs, among which are many familiar
names, account for more than 15 percent of all foreign assets controlled by all
MNCs, and for 22 percent of total sales by MNCs. These large MNCs are based almost exclusively
in advanced industrialized countries; ninety-nine of the 100 largest firms are
from the United States, Western Europe, or Japan and more than 5/6ths of all
parent corporations are based in advanced industrial countries (see table 5.3). Parent corporations are not exclusively a
developed country phenomenon, however.
Hong Kong, China, South Korea, Venezuela, Mexico, and Brazil are also
home to MNC parent firms, but these firms are considerably smaller than
developed country firms. Only one MNC
parent based in a developing country, Petroleos de Venezuela, ranks among the
world’s 100 largest. The fifty largest
MNCs from developing countries control only $105 billion of foreign assets,
less than ten percent of the assets controlled by the 50 largest developed country
MNCs. The distribution is reversed when we consider the affiliates. Developing countries host more than 355,324
MNC affiliates, while advanced industrialized countries host only 94,269
(UNCTAD 2000, 11-13). Within the
developing world, MNC affiliates are
Table 5.2: The Fifty Largest
MNCs, Ranked by Foreign Assets
Firm Country Industry Foreign Total
Foreign
Assets Assets Employment
General
Electric
|
United
States
|
Electronics
|
97.4
|
304.0
|
111,000
|
Ford Motor
Company
|
United
States
|
Automotive
|
72.5
|
275.4
|
174,105
|
Royal Dutch
Shell
|
Netherlands/UK
|
Petroleum
|
70
|
115
|
65,000
|
General
Motors
|
United
States
|
Automotive
|
|
|
|
Exxon Corp
|
United
States
|
Petroleum
|
54.6
|
96.1
|
|
Toyota
|
Japan
|
Automotive
|
41.8
|
105.0
|
|
IBM
|
United
States
|
Computer
|
39.9
|
81.5
|
134,815
|
Volkswagen
Group
|
Germany
|
Automotive
|
|
57.0
|
133,906
|
Nestle S.A.
|
Switzerland
|
Food and
Beverages
|
31.6
|
47.6
|
219,442
|
Daimler-Benz
|
Germany
|
Automotive
|
30.9
|
76.2
|
74,802
|
Mobil
|
United
States
|
Petroleum
|
30.4
|
43.6
|
22,200
|
Fiat Spa
|
Italy
|
Automotive
|
30
|
69.1
|
94,877
|
Hoechst AG
|
Germany
|
Chemicals
|
29.0
|
34.0
|
|
Asea Brown
Boveri (ABB)
|
Switzerland
|
Electrical
Equipment
|
|
29.8
|
200,574
|
Bayer AG
|
Germany
|
Chemicals
|
|
30.3
|
|
Elf
Aquitaine SA
|
France
|
Petroleum
|
26.7
|
42.0
|
40,500
|
Nissan Motor
|
Japan
|
Automotive
|
26.5
|
57.6
|
|
Unilever
|
Netherlands/Uk
|
Food and Bev
|
25.6
|
30.8
|
262,840
|
Siemens AG
|
Germany
|
Electronics
|
25.6
|
67.1
|
201,141
|
Roche
Holding AG
|
Switzerland
|
Pharmaceuticals
|
|
37.6
|
41,832
|
Sony Corp
|
Japan
|
Electronics
|
|
48.2
|
|
Mitsubishi
|
Japan
|
Diversified
|
21.9
|
67.1
|
|
Seagram
|
Canada
|
Beverages
|
21.8
|
22.2
|
|
Honda Motor
|
Japan
|
Automotive
|
21.5
|
36.5
|
|
BMW AG
|
Germany
|
Automotive
|
20.3
|
31.8
|
52,149
|
Alcatel
|
France
|
Electronics
|
20.3
|
41.9
|
|
Philips
Electronics
|
Netherlands
|
Electronics
|
20.1
|
25.5
|
206,236
|
News Corp
|
Australia
|
Media
|
20.0
|
30.7
|
|
Phillip Morris
|
United
States
|
Food/Tobacco
|
19.4
|
55.9
|
|
British Petroleum
|
UK
|
Petroleum
|
19.2
|
32.6
|
37,600
|
Hewlett-Packard
|
United
States
|
Electronics
|
18.5
|
31.7
|
|
Total SA
|
France
|
Petrloeum
|
|
25.2
|
|
Renault SA
|
France
|
Automotive
|
18.3
|
34.9
|
45,860
|
Cable and
Wireless Plc
|
UK
|
Telecommunication
|
|
21.6
|
33,740
|
Mitsui &Co.
Ltd
|
Japan
|
Diversified
|
17.9
|
55.5
|
|
Rhone-Poulenc SA
|
France
|
Chemicals/Pharmaceuticals
|
17.8
|
27.5
|
|
Viag SA
|
Germany
|
Diversified
|
17.4
|
32.7
|
|
BASF AG
|
Germany
|
Chemicals
|
|
26.8
|
|
Itochu Corp
|
Japan
|
Trading
|
16.7
|
56.8
|
2,600
|
Nassho Iwei Corp
|
Japan
|
Trading
|
16.6
|
40.4
|
2,068
|
Du Pont
|
United States
|
Chemicals
|
16.6
|
42.7
|
|
Diageo Plc
|
UK
|
Beverages
|
|
29.7
|
63,761
|
Novartis
|
Switzerland
|
Pharmaceuticals/Chemicals
|
16.0
|
36.7
|
71,403
|
Sumitomo Corp
|
Japan
|
Trading/machinery
|
15.4
|
43.0
|
|
ENI Group
|
Italy
|
Petroleum
|
14.6
|
49.4
|
23,239
|
Chevron Corp
|
United
States
|
Petroleum
|
14.3
|
35.5
|
8,610
|
Dow Chemical
|
United States
|
Chemicals
|
14.3
|
23.6
|
|
Texaco Inc
|
United
States
|
Petroleum
|
14.1
|
29.6
|
|
BCE Inc
|
Canada
|
Telecommunication
|
13.6
|
28.2
|
|
Xerox
|
United
States
|
Photo Equipment
|
13.5
|
27.7
|
|
Source: United Nations Conference on Trade and
Development, 1999.
Table
5.3: Parent Corporations and Affiliates By Region
Parent Corporations Foreign Affiliates
Based
in Economy Located in Economy
Developed Economies
|
|
|
Western Europe
|
37,580
|
61,594
|
United States
|
3,387
|
19,103
|
Japan
|
4,334
|
3,321
|
Developing Economies
|
|
|
Africa
|
167
|
3,669
|
Latin America and Caribbean
|
2,019
|
24,345
|
Asia
|
9,883
|
327,310
|
Central and Eastern Europe
|
2,150
|
239,927
|
Source: UNCTAD 2000, 11-13.
highly concentrated in a relatively small set of countries. Thirteen countries in East Asia and Latin America host 331,748 MNC affiliates, about half of the total affiliates worldwide. China alone hosts 235,681 affiliates. MNCs have also invested heavily in Eastern and Central Europe during the 1990s, creating a total of 239,927 affiliates in this region. Here too affiliates are concentrated in a few countries; the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Poland host 135,997 of the affiliates active in this region. While these figures on the location of affiliates are interesting, they are misleading to some extent. As we saw in chapter four, the vast majority of foreign direct investment flows into advanced industrialized countries rather than the developing world. Thus, even though there are more affiliates based in developing countries than in advanced industrialized countries, the affiliates created in advanced industrialized countries tend to be larger and more capital intensive than the affiliates created in developing countries.
For
what specific purposes do firms engage in foreign direct investment? MNC
investment can be divided into three broad categories. First, MNCs engage in crossborder investment
to gain secure access to supplies of natural resources. For example, the American copper mining firm
Anaconda made large direct investments in mining operations in Chile in order
to secure copper supplies for production done in the United States. Indeed, as table 5.4 illustrates, petroleum
and mining is the third most important industry represented in the top 100
MNCs, with 11 of the largest firms engaged in either oil production or mining.
Second, MNCs
invest across borders to gain access to foreign markets. Much of the cross-border investment in auto
production undertaken within the advanced industrialized world fits into this
category. During the 1980s and early
1990s, Japanese
Table 5.4: Industry Composition
of the Top 100 MNCs
1990 1998
Electronics/electrical
equipment/computers
|
14
|
17
|
Motor Vehicle and
Parts
|
13
|
14
|
Petroleum
(exploration, refining, distribution) and Mining
|
13
|
11
|
Food, Beverages,
Tobacco
|
9
|
10
|
Chemicals
|
12
|
8
|
Pharmaceuticals
|
6
|
8
|
Diversified
|
2
|
6
|
Telecommunications
|
2
|
6
|
Trading
|
7
|
4
|
Retailing
|
-
|
3
|
Utilities
|
-
|
3
|
Metals
|
6
|
2
|
Media
|
2
|
2
|
Construction
|
4
|
1
|
Machinery/engineering
|
3
|
-
|
Other
|
7
|
5
|
Total
|
100
|
100
|
Source: UNCTAD 2000, 78.
and German
automotive MNCs such as Toyota, Nissan, Honda, BMW, and Mercedes
built production
facilities in the United States in response to concerns that barriers to market
access would limit the number of cars they would be allowed to export into the
American economy from Japanese and German plants. During the 1960s, many American MNCs made
direct investments in the European Union to gain access to the common market
being created there. As table 5.4
indicates, the auto industry is the second most heavily represented industry
among the largest MNCs, accounting for 14 of the top 100 MNCs.
Third, MNCs make cross-border investments to improve the efficiency of
their operations, by rationalizing production and trying to exploit economies
of specialization and scope. An
increasingly large share of cross-border investment in manufacturing fits into
this category. In electronics and
computers as well as in the auto industry, firms allocate different elements of
the production process to different parts of the world. In computers, electronics, and electrical
equipment, for example, which account for seventeen of the largest 100 MNCs
(see table 5.4), the human and physical capital intensive stages of production
such as design and chip fabrication, are performed in the advanced
industrialized countries, while the more labor-intensive assembly stages of
production are performed in developing countries. In the auto industry, the capital intensive
design and production of individual parts such as body panels, engines, and
transmissions is performed in developed countries, and the more labor-intensive
assembly of the individual components into automobiles is performed in
developing countries.
Multinational
corporations’ activities in the postwar international economy have evolved over
time. It is common to divide this
evolution into two distinct periods, the immediate postwar period spanning the
years 1945 to 1960 and a second period since 1960. Two features characterized the immediate
postwar period. First, American firms
dominated foreign direct investment.
Concerned with postwar reconstruction and unwilling to risk the balance
of payments consequences of capital outflows, European and Japanese governments
had little interest in encouraging outward direct investment. As a consequence, American firms dominated
MNC activity, accounting for about two thirds of the new affiliates created in
this period. Second, the bulk of MNC
investment during this period was oriented toward Europe for the purpose of
manufacturing. The push to invest in
Europe was given additional impetus at the end of the 1950s by the creation of
the European Economic Community, and thus the early 1960s saw a rapid increase
in the amount of market-oriented investment by American firms in the Common
Market
countries. Other direct investments
flowed to developing countries, Canada, and Australia for natural resource
extraction. In short, American MNCs
engaged primarily in market- and natural resource-oriented foreign direct
investment dominated the immediate postwar period.
Both
of these characteristics of MNC activity have changed dramatically since
1960. The early dominance of American
firms has been increasingly diminished as European and Japanese firms began to
engage in foreign direct investment. The
increased role of other industrialized nations has more recently been
accompanied by the emergence of foreign direct investment by MNCs based in the
Asian NICs and in Latin America. Thus,
while American firms continue to play a large role, they are not nearly as
dominant today as they were in the early postwar years. At the same time, the relative importance of
market- and natural resource-oriented direct investment has fallen and that of
efficiency-oriented investment has risen.
As Dunning (1996) notes, MNCs increasingly view “each of their foreign
affiliates and, frequently, their associated suppliers and industrial
customers, not as self-contained entities, but as part of a regional or global
network of activities. New investments
are increasingly undertaken as part of an integrated international production
system.” The shift to efficiency-oriented investments and integrated
international production systems has been made possible in large part by
developments in communications technology and, as we saw in chapter four, by
the reduction in trade barriers achieved through the GATT process. In summary,
during the last fifty years multinational corporations have grown to play a
centrally important role in the international economy. MNCs are, in many respects, the driving force
behind the deepening integration of the global economy. The central importance of MNCs in the
contemporary international economy raises a large number of issues that we
explore in the pages that follow. Most
of these issues can be subsumed under a single question: What are the economic and political
consequences of MNC activity? To answer
this question we look first at the economics of multinational corporations,
examining why firms engage in foreign direct investment and how FDI affects
economic activity in the countries that host it. We then turn our attention to the political
economy of MNCs, examining the nature of the bargaining relationship between
MNCs and host-country governments and governments’ efforts, unsuccessful to
date, to craft an international investment regime.
The
Costs and Benefits of MNC Activity
How are host countries affected by MNC activity? While it is clear that
MNCs are motivated to engage in foreign direct investment to raise their
profitability, it is less obvious what impact these investments have on the
countries that receive them. In fact,
most of the controversy surrounding MNC activity arises from disputes over how
foreign direct investment affects the host country. Some argue that FDI is highly beneficial to
the host country, while others argue that MNCs have a negative impact on host
countries, particularly in the developing world. Here we look closely at two well-developed
perspectives on the impact of foreign direct investment on host countries and
then briefly consider what the existing empirical evidence suggests about the
accuracy of these competing perspectives.
The Benign model argues that MNCs make a significant
contribution to economic development.
Foreign direct investment is an important mechanism through which
savings are transferred from the advanced industrialized world to the developing
world. Because developing countries
usually have low savings, FDI can usefully add to the capital available for
physical investment. Moreover, because
MNCs create fixed investments, this form of cross-border capital flow is not
subject to the problems often posed by financial capital flows. Fixed investment is substantially less
volatile than financial capital flows, and thus does not generate the kinds of
boom and bust cycles we saw in chapter 8.
In addition, because MNCs invest by creating domestic affiliates, direct
investment does not raise host countries’ external indebtedness. Of the many possible ways in which savings
can be transferred to the developing world, therefore, direct investment might
be the most stable and least burdensome for the recipient countries.
The benign model also suggests that MNCs are important vehicles for the
transfer of technology to host countries.
Because MNCs control proprietary assets, which are often based on
specialized knowledge, the investments they make in developing countries often
lead to this knowledge being transferred to indigenous firms. In Malaysia, for example, Motorola Malaysia
transferred the technology required to produce a particular type of printed
circuit board to a Malaysian firm, which then developed the capacity to produce
these circuit boards on its own (Moran 1999, 77-8). In the absence of the technology transfer,
the indigenous firm would not have been able to produce these products. Technology transfer can in turn generate
significant positive externalities with wider implications for development (see
Graham 1996, 123-130). Externalities
arise when economic actors in the host country that are not directly involved
in the MNC-local affiliate technology transfer also gain from this transaction. If the Malaysian Motorola affiliate, for
example, was able to use the technology it acquired from Motorola to produce
inputs for other Malaysian firms at a lower cost than these inputs were
available elsewhere, then the technology transfer would have a positive
externality on the Malaysian economy.
In addition to transferring technology, the benign model suggests that
MNCs transfer managerial expertise to developing countries. Greater experience at managing large firms
allows MNC personnel to organize production and coordinate the activities of
multiple enterprises more efficiently than host country managers. This knowledge is applied to the host country
affiliates, allowing them to operate more efficiently as well. Indigenous managers in these affiliates can
then move to indigenous firms, spreading managerial expertise into the host
country.
Finally, the benign model suggests that MNCs enable developing country
producers to gain access to marketing networks.
When direct investments are made as part of a global production strategy,
the local affiliates of the MNC and the domestic firms that supply the MNC
affiliate become integrated into a global marketing chain.
This opens up
export opportunities that indigenous producers would not otherwise have. The Malaysian firm to which Motorola
transferred the printed circuit board technology, for example, wound up
supplying not only Motorola Malaysia, but also began to supply these components
to eleven Motorola plants worldwide.
These opportunities would not have arisen had the firm not been able to
link up with Motorola Malaysia.
The Malign model focuses on many of the same elements as the
benign model, but argues that these factors often operate to the detriment of
host country economic development.
First, rather than transferring savings to developing countries, the
malign model argues that MNCs reduce domestic savings. Savings are reduced in two ways. First, it is argued that MNCs often borrow on
the host country capital market rather than bring capital from their home
country. MNC investment therefore
“crowds out” rather than adding to domestic investment. Second, it is suggested that MNCs earn rents—
above normal profits—on their products and repatriate most of these earnings. Host country consumers therefore pay too much
for the goods they buy, with negative consequences on individual savings, while
MNC profits, which could potentially be a source of savings and investment in
the host country, are transferred back to the home country. The amount of domestic savings available to
finance projects therefore falls.
The malign
model also argues that MNCs exert tight control over technology and managerial
positions, preventing the transfer of both.
The logic here is simple. As we
saw above, one of the principal reasons for MNC investment arises from the
desire to maintain control over proprietary assets. Given this, it is indeed hard to understand
why an MNC would make a large fixed investment in order to retain control over
proprietary technology, and then once having done so begin to transfer this
technology to host country firms.
Managerial expertise is not readily transferred either, in large part
because MNCs are reluctant to hire host-country residents into top-level
managerial positions. Thus, the second
purported benefit of MNC—the transfer of technology and managerial
expertise—can be stymied by the very logic that causes MNCs to undertake FDI.
Finally, the malign model suggests that MNCs can drive domestic
producers out of business. This can
happen in one of two ways. On the one
hand, domestic firms producing in the same sector will face increased
competition once an MNC begins selling in the domestic market. Using best practices for management and state
of the art technology, MNCs can often under-price local firms, thereby driving
them out of business. Second, MNCs often
desire to assemble their finished goods from imported components. As a result, domestic input producers in the
same industry will find that as the domestic producers they supply are driven
out of business, they have no one to sell their intermediate goods. Thus, local input suppliers can also be
driven out of business by MNCs.
The benign and the malign models depict dramatically different
consequences from MNC/TNC investment in developing country economies. Which of these two models is correct? The short answer is that both are; foreign
direct investment is sometimes beneficial for and at other times detrimental to
the host countries. Two studies, now
somewhat outdated, are suggestive in this regard. One study examined 88 MNC affiliates
operating in six countries (Lall and Streeten 1977). The authors found that in two-thirds of the
cases foreign direct investment had a positive impact on the host country, and
in one-third of the cases the impact was negative. A similar study was conducted about ten years
later. Focusing on 50 foreign direct
investments, this study found that between half and three quarters of the foreign
investments yielded net benefits to the host countries, while one-quarter to
one-half of the projects imposed net costs onto the host country (Encarnation
and Wells 1986). Thus, foreign direct
investment sometimes operates in the manner suggested by the benign model, and
at other times it operates as the malign model suggests.
What
determines whether any particular investment will be beneficial or detrimental
to the host country? It is extremely
difficult to say anything systematic or conclusive in response to this
question. A range of considerations are
important, including the specific agreement between the host-country government
and the MNC upon which the investment is based.
While any broad generalizations must therefore be treated with
considerable caution, one can suggest that some types of investment begin with
a bias against host country development while other types of investment do not
carry an initial bias. Market oriented
and natural resource investments both carry biases that can limit the
contribution they make to economic development in host countries. First, both types of investment take place
under conditions of limited competition.
Foreign affiliates in the extractive industries often gain monopoly
control over the resource deposits of a given country, for example, while
affiliates producing for the host-country market are often protected from
external competition by high tariffs.
The absence of competition results in large rents accruing to firms
operating in these areas, with associated efficiency losses for the host
country. Moreover, both types of investment
can have a negative impact on domestic producers in the host country. UNCTAD suggests, for example, that recent
investments by MNCs in copper mining in Chile may have substituted for
investments that otherwise would have been made by the Chilean national copper
company (CODELCO), “which is the largest copper mining enterprise in the world
and operates with state-of-the-art technology” (UNCTAD 1999, 173). Finally, neither resource oriented nor market
oriented investment offers many opportunities for domestic producers to link
into international marketing networks.
For all of these reasons we might expect host countries to be most
likely to suffer costs from natural resource and market-oriented investments.
Efficiency-oriented investments seem to carry fewer of the biases and
offer the greatest chance that MNC activity will have a positive impact on host
countries. The industries in which these
investments occur are usually quite competitive internationally, hence the
MNC’s drive for cost reduction measures, and the level of rents is
correspondingly lower. Such investments
can (but don’t always) create backward linkages to domestic input producers,
and thus can promote rather than retard local firm growth. In particular, efficiency-oriented investments
often “crowd-in” rather than “crowd out” investments by domestic firms. For example, it has been estimated that
Intel’s decision to construct a microprocessor plant in Costa Rica will likely
give rise to additional investments by 40 Costa Rican firms (UNCTAD 1999,
172). Finally, the international
orientation of such firms creates opportunities for local firms to link
themselves to global marketing networks.
The research reported by Encarnation and Wells (1986) is consistent with
the notion that efficiency-oriented investments contain fewer of the biases
against development that are present in natural resource and market oriented
investments. All of the export-oriented
projects in the sample of MNC affiliates that they examined provided benefits
to the host country. For all of these
reasons we might expect host countries to benefit the most from
efficiency-oriented investments.
The case of Singer Sewing Machines experience in Taiwan is suggestive
of the potential benefits available through well-managed foreign direct
investment. Singer first began producing
in Taiwan in 1964.[1] At the time there were a number of local
sewing machine producers using old technology and lacking standardization and
therefore unable to compete in international markets. As a condition of Singer’s investment, the
Taiwanese government imposed domestic content requirements, insisting that
Singer source 83 percent of its parts from Taiwanese producers within one year. In addition, the Taiwanese government imposed
substantial conditions to ensure technology transfers. Singer was required to provide the local
parts producers with standardized blueprints, and make available technical
experts to assist in local firms’ efforts to produce the specified parts. In addition, Singer was obliged to allow
Taiwanese sewing machine producers to use the same parts it sourced from local
parts producers at a cost close to the world price for these parts. Finally, an export requirement was imposed; Singer
was required to increase its exports from Taiwan rapidly.
Singer complied with all of these requirements. Technical and management experts were
dispatched to train local parts producers and to reorganize the production
system within Taiwan. Technical
assistance was also provided to local sewing machine producers—the very firms
that comprised Singer’s competition—at no cost to these firms. Blueprints and part specifications were
provided to all local parts producers, thereby allowing them to work to common
specifications and standards. Finally,
Singer held classes for local parts producers in the technical and managerial
aspects of the business.
As a direct result of these measures, substantial transfers of
technology occurred, and significant backward linkages between the final sewing
machine producers and the parts suppliers occurred. By the late 1960s Singer was sourcing all of
the parts for its sewing machines produced in Taiwan from Taiwanese firms
(except the needles). Moreover, 86
percent of Singer’s local production was exported. In addition, Taiwanese sewing machine
producers became more competitive internationally. As local parts became standardized and of
greater quality, Taiwanese sewing machine producers also became able to export
to foreign markets.
In summary, MNC/TNC activity is sometimes beneficial for host country
economic development, and at other times is detrimental to such
development. One might suggest that
natural resource investments are the least likely to offer substantial benefits
to host countries, while efficiency oriented investments are the most likely to
offer substantial benefits to host countries.
Market oriented investments are likely to fall somewhere in between
these two types, sometimes offering benefits, and at other times imposing
costs. It is important to re-emphasize
the tentativeness of these broad generalizations. The point must be made that MNC/TNC activity
has historically been subject to political considerations. As a consequence, the impact of any
particular investment on any particular host country is shaped by the
particular agreement between the firm and the host country government. These agreements can transform a natural
resource investment into a highly beneficial proposition for a host country,
and they can transform an efficiency-oriented investment into a highly costly
one. In other words, while the preceding
discussion is suggestive, the effect that any particular foreign direct
investment will have on any particular host country will depend greatly on the
specific details of the case.
References
Caves, Richard E. 1996. Multinational
Enterprise and Economic Analysis.
Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Dunning,
John H. 1996. “Re-evaluating the
Benefits of Foreign Direct Investment,” in Companies
without Borders: Transnational
Corporations in the 1990s, edited by UNCTAD. (London: International Thomson Business Press), pp.
73-101.
Graham, Edward M. 1996. Global Corporations and National Governments.
Washington, D.C.: Institute for
International Economics.
Hymer, Stephen. 1976. The international operations of national firms: a study of direct foreign investment. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Kindleberger, Charles P. 1969. Six Lectures on Direct Investment. New Haven:
Yale University Press.
Kobrin, Stephen. 1987. “Testing the Bargaining Hypothesis in the
Manufacturing Sector in Developing Countries,” International
Organization 41 (autumn): 609-638.
Moran, Theodore H. 1999. Foreign Direct Investment and Development: The New Policy Agenda for Developing Countries and Economies in
Transition. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
Moran, Theodore H. 1974. Multinational corporations and the politics of dependence: Copper in Chile. Princeton, N.J., Princeton
University Press.
Stopford, John M. 1996. “The Growing Interdependence Between
Transnational
Corporations and Governments,”
in Companies without Borders: Transnational Corporations in the 1990s, edited by UNCTAD. (London: International Thomson Business Press), pp.
255-79.
Teece, David J. 1993, “The
Multinational Enterprise: Market Failure
and Market Power Considerations,” in The Theory
of Transnational Corporations, John Dunning, editor. New York:
Routledge, pp. 163-182.
United
Nations Conference on Trade and Development. 2000. World Investment Report: Cross-border
Mergers and Acquisitions and Development.
Geneva: The United Nations.
United Nations Conference on Trade and
Development. 1999. World Investment Report: Foreign
Direct Investment and the Challenge of Development. Geneva: The United Nations.
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. 1995. World Investment Report: Transnational Corporations and Competitiveness. Geneva: The United Nations.
Vernon, Raymond. 1971. Sovereignty at Bay: the Multinational Spread of U.S.
Enterprises. New
York: Basic Books.
All sites are working.. This is great thing. A huge thanks from my side
ReplyDeleteAluminium Scaffolding Rental